PRIVATIZATION IN NACC COUNTRIES Defence Industry Experiences and Policies and Related Experiences in Other Fields COLLOQUIUM 1994 ********* COLLOQUE 1994 PRIVATISATION DANS LES PAYS DU CCNA Experiences et politiques des industries de defense et experiences comparables dans d'autres secteurs Colloquium 29-30 June, 1 July 1994 Brussels --------------------------------------------------------- PROBLEMS AND PROSPECTS FOR PRIVATIZATION IN POST-COMMUNIST COUNTRIES Salvatore Zecchini The fact that privatisation of state-owned entreprises - in both the East and West - has become a priority for governments is not a historical coincidence, says Salvatore Zecchini. Governments are now realising that privatization is a powerful instrument to help them revive economic growth. Privatization is not the main solution to problems affecting the defence industry. But it can be an important component of a multifaceted strategy. In the face of conflicting pressures, it is likely that privatization in the next five years will continue to be a gradual process and not the determinant factor behind the expansion of the private sector. Salvatore Zecchini is Assistant Secretary-General of the OECD in Paris, and Director of the Centre for Co-operation with the Economies in Transition. It is not a casual coincidence of history if, in this decade, privatisation stands high on the political and economic agenda of both several OECD countries and all the post-communist countries. It is rather the result of a fundamental conclusion drawn by governments in both areas, i.e. that privatisation is a major instrument to realise important welfare gains for the country as a whole because it revives economic initiative and promotes innovation and higher productivity, all factors that lead to sustained economic growth. A concurrent consideration common to both OECD countries and post-communist countries is that privatisation can help the government to generate resources or to save resources for the purpose of reducing budget deficits. Not only in ultimate goals but also in the privatisation methods there are similarities as both country groups are privatising similar categories of public assets, i.e. land, manufacturing enterprises, financial institutions and individual production facilities. In spite of these similarities, privatisation in the CEECs and NIS is in many respects a process and a problem different from that which can currently be seen in the OECD area. It is not just a difference in the absolute and relative scale of this operation since the CEECs and NIS have to privatise the bulk of their productive assets. There are other more important differences. The economic backdrop against which privatisation has been taking place is much more difficult than in the OECD area as all the reforming economies have experienced a deep reduction in the level of economic activity, living standards and savings. In addition, they have had to pursue a much more diversified set of privatisation objectives than merely disposing of public assets at the best price. They also lacked an institutional, legal and financial infrastructure that could ease the ownership transfer, protect private ownership and promote entrepreneurship. Last but not least, privatisation had to be carried out in a context of scarcity of domestic private capital and severe shortage of entrepreneurship and management skills. All these differences make it doubtful whether these economies can duplicate or draw many useful lessons from the recent privatisation experience of OECD countries. To deal with the unusual aspects of their privatisation problems, the CEECs and NIS have had to do a fair amount of experimentation, to draw on each other's experience, and to carefully blend foreign technical expertise with their own assessment of the internal constraints to privatisation. But in one area that is essential to support privatisation and in which these countries have to take measures which are not needed in the OECD countries, their action has been below their possibilities. This area is the rapid reform of the legal and institutional system which presides over the carrying-out of economic activities. Instead of continuing to dwell on a comparative analysis of the privatisation issues, I will concentrate my remarks on the state of privatisation in the CEECs and NIS, on the main problems which hamper privatisation, with a specific attention to the defence industry, and on the prospects for the next few years. At the beginning of the transformation process, privatisation, together with economic liberalisation, was hailed by governments and people as the driving force to accelerate the change of the economic system and to inject dynamism into these lagging economies. In fact, after 3 or 4 years this expectation has not materialised in any of these countries in spite of the considerable planning effort. In the last three years, it is the rapid output expansion in the private enterprise sector that has been the main factor to reverse or to slow down the general economic decline. In Poland, Hungary and the Czech Republic the private sector already contributes more than half to GDP formation. Such an expansion, however, has not critically depended on the pace and extent of enterprise privatisation. For instance, Poland has privatised only about 20% of its public firms and Hungary only 1/3 in terms of asset value. The disposal of individual or relatively small production assets outside enterprise privatisation has instead been important to allow many private entrepreneurs to build a minimum of capital base rapidly. As the private sector could not afford large investment outlays, it has developed in low-capital-intensity activities in which it could use relatively small production facilities or assets, previously in public hands, in a new enterprise context in which it could achieve sharp productivity gains. If in many segments of the services sector private enterprises are predominant in number and output and if the share of services in national output has risen sharply in all reforming economies at the expense mostly of industry's share, this is also due to the flow of relatively small public assets into private hands, while major assets and enterprises have remained in the public domain. Of course, within this general picture of the role of privatisation, important differences exist. Progress in privatisation has been very uneven in terms of both countries and types of assets. Among the CEECs, the Czech Republic has progressed more than the other countries with more than 60% of public enterprisesÕ assets already privatised or in the process of being privatised in the on-going second wave of voucher privatisation. Russia has been the most rapid country in privatisation: about 40% of large enterprises and more than half of small enterprises have changed hands in less than two years. Estonia and Lithuania have also advanced considerably in ÒlargeÓ and ÒsmallÓ privatisation. Ukraine and other NIS are instead lagging behind, still remaining at the beginning of this process. The so-called "small privatisation", namely the one involving small firms operating in retail trade, catering services, transport and small construction businesses as well as small production units, is very advanced if not already completed in some countries. Furthermore, in Poland and Hungary, privatisation (de jure or de facto) of production assets as opposed to entire enterprises has been quite important, accounting for about half of privatised production assets. This has been performed, for instance, through "liquidation", whereby production assets are transferred to new entrepreneurs while the old public firm disappears and its liabilities are taken over by the public sector. Considerable delays instead characterise privatisation of large firms, with the exception of the Czech Republic and Russia which are the only countries that have made substantial progress in this respect. The ownership change has not affected all economic sectors to the same extent. Heavy industries, utilities, energy, major transport firms and major chemical industries have so far largely escaped privatisation for reasons that cannot be related to the notion that potential market failures justify retaining these firms under direct public control. To this effect, several countries have instead used the argument of the strategic nature of these industries or sectors; they have not considered the possibility of obtaining more efficient enterprises through privatisation coupled with a new model of industry regulation. Only lately there has been a change in attitude in Hungary, Poland and the Czech republic. They have privatised or are privatising public utilities, such as power generation, telecommunications and water supply. This can be explained with the increasing pressure on these governments to generate additional resources for the public budget and to improve the quality of these services and management. Banks and other financial institutions have been privatised to a very limited extent, particularly because they require extensive support by the government due to the insolvency of many of their debtors belonging to the public enterprise sector. With the exception of Poland where agriculture was not nationalised under the previous regime, agricultural land is still to a large extent under public or old-co-operative ownership. Problems in partition of land and in some countries the unsettled question of restitution to original owners are adding to the delays. In those countries in which agricultural land ownership has been transferred to peasants or co-operatives, the impact on production has been generally negative so far, because the new private farmers have not been able to acquire needed farm equipment and inputs, and to develop models of farm enterprise which are a viable alternative to the old co-operatives. In spite of being relatively easier to implement, privatisation of housing is far from complete because of delays in reforming rent level determination and house purchase financing. The only exception is Hungary where a favourable financing scheme has accelerated this privatisation. Overall, a large number of public assets are now in private hands in CEECs and Russia, but in spite of the considerable amount of preparatory work which has been done in most post-communist countries, the bulk of industrial, banking and large-scale enterprises has still to be privatised. Only the Czech Republic and Russia seem seriously determined to press ahead for the completion of this process in a short period. As to the other countries, it is not clear whether they will overcome the many obstacles encountered in this process and what will be the share of public ownership in the enterprise sector at the end of this decade and its importance for the development of these economies. At this juncture in the transformation of the post-communist economies what are the main problems hampering progress in privatisation? Clearly, privatisation has not been hindered by the particular approach followed by these countries. After the initial professions of faith in one or the other approach, these governments have soon come to recognise that to deal with the complex reality of public firms dismissal it is necessary to use all available methods. All countries are currently resorting to a multiplicity of approaches, although there are differences among countries as to the choice of the predominant approach. Mass privatisation, i.e. the unrequited transfer of ownership to the population at large, has either been adopted or is being considered by all countries. This is the only instrument that can accelerate the pace of privatisation because it does not discriminate among sections of the population in terms of who would benefit. Moreover, it avoids the difficulty raised by the capital requirement for the acquisition of ownership or the difficulties of having to restructure a firm before it is sold. Therefore, it is not surprising that privatisation has progressed rapidly in those countries in which this method has been applied more extensively. The Czech Republic and Russia, which are the front-runners in privatisation, have transferred more than half of the book value of privatised firms through mass privatisation vouchers. Hungary, which has had difficulties in making privatisation advance, has recently introduced generous credit facilities for the purchase of firms by its population in order to obtain some of the benefits stemming from mass privatisation. Through this approach it can quicken the pace of ownership transfer. It is evident that the public sector of these countries is not in a position to carry out a reorganisation or operational restructuring of its firms to make them competitive in the market place. These governments even lack the means to implement a financial restructuring aimed at helping the firm to achieve a balanced capital structure by reducing its excess leverage (i.e. eliminating its debt overhang). The public owner can instead be expected to "corporatise" its firms, and to break up large firms. Apart from these tasks, restructuring is to be obtained by private entrepreneurs once ownership has been transferred to their hands. Management contracts are just an approximation to this result. Poland is the country that more than any other has been engaged in pre-privatisation reorganisation, but this has been possible only for a relatively small number of firms. Extending this approach to the rest of large enterprises would imply a significant protraction of privatisation. Management or employee buy-outs are the second most used instrument for privatisation. They have been linked to voucher schemes for mass privatisation or sales under preferential conditions. Both options have been widely applied in Russia, Poland and Lithuania on the request of the enterprises themselves. Trade sales, i.e. the sale of firms to strategic investors through public tenders, closed tenders, direct sales, or various forms of auctions, are more difficult to implement than other methods because they require extensive preparation of the sale, a measure of restructuring of the enterprise to be privatised, and adequate financial support. Among the reforming countries, Hungary is the one which has chosen to rely mostly on this method as it accounts for about 3/4 of privatised firms by book value. As long as it followed only this approach Hungary made relatively slow progress in privatisation. If the approach to privatisation is not at present the main problem in making progress, other factors constitute impediments. First, the initial enthusiasm and social and political pressures for privatisation are fading away in several countries, including Hungary and Poland. Political consensus is lacking because of the persistent fear of adverse social consequences of post-privatisation restructuring. Two consequences have been a source of particular concern: a) the radical change that privatisation induces in the distribution of wealth; this represents a major shock for societies used to decades of "egalitarianism"; b) the restructuring of the labour force and social services provided by the privatised firm which tends to eliminate the job and social guarantees of the old regime. In the face of these concerns, governments tend to link privatisation to the fulfilment of a multitude of objectives other than achieving efficiency gains. These include distributing public assets to all the population since all have contributed to their build-up, creating new employment opportunities or limiting job destruction, obtaining guarantees of development of the firm's capital, favouring new entrepreneurs, and maximising proceeds. These aims are not mutually compatible, and cannot be achieved by privatisation alone, even if the approach is diversified into alternative methods that are applied to different portions of public assets. To the extent that governments have not been able to establish an order of priority between conflicting aims, a compromise has been the necessary outcome and the easiest compromise of all was initially to delay the process. Of course, delays are not a viable solution as they lead to a deterioration of assets, abuse through mismanagement or misappropriation, and eventually to liquidation of firms. Thus, after the initial stage, mass privatisation became the main solution to political and social impediments. But this is not the best solution for the economy because the development of these economies demands a certain degree of concentration of enterprise ownership in the hands of entrepreneurs who are fully committed to steer the course of their enterprises. Hence, a second stage of ownership adjustment is necessary after privatisation and this requires well functioning capital markets. Nevertheless, as a second-best solution, mass privatisation is the easiest approach, and at the present juncture a number of lagging countries are moving in this direction. They are actually forced to privatise because there is less room in their budgets to sustain the cost of supporting public enterprises and past delays in privatisation have not led, as expected, to lower hardship for people and easier recovery for these economies. Even under these conditions, progress will depend on the capacity of governments to develop cost-effective social policies to smooth the enterprise restructuring process. In this respect, two conditions must be fulfilled: a) that the level of economic activity starts rising again; b) that an active labour market policy is developed. The second major problem is represented by the inadequacies of the institutional and financial framework of the economy and of privatisation itself. At the institutional level, the transfer of ownership is still taking place in a context in which property rights are not adequately protected and private enterprises operate in an uncertain legal and regulatory environment. Enforcement of contractual obligations is doubtful and costly, while the hold of the old bureaucracy over economic activities is still pervasive. At the financial level, privatised enterprises face difficulties in meeting their financing requirements and in diversifying their capital sources in order to correct their currently-high financial leverage. Credit allocation by banks is still distorted in favour of firms holding public guarantees. The possibility of reducing enterprises' debt ratio through debt/equity swaps with the creditor banks is limited because of the weak capital base of most banks. Financial markets are still at an early stage of development and are dominated by the financial instruments issued by the government. The general attitude of these countries has been to give priority to solving industrial crises on a case-by-case basis. Less emphasis has been placed on improving rapidly the economic environment, in easing rigidities on the employment of labour force, and in developing competitive markets for products and factors of production. Under these framework conditions, it is difficult to expect that privatised enterprises can become competitive soon and that privatisation can bring about an early renewal of these economies. Linked to this problem is a third one, i.e. the failure of privatisation in all the post-communist countries to attract large flows of foreign capital. Although there have been some restrictions or discriminations against foreign investors for the purpose of preventing a sell-off to foreigners, these measures do not seem to have constituted a major disincentive. For instance, even in the case of Hungary, which is the largest recipient of FDI, only one third of foreign capital has been invested in the purchase of public firms, while the largest part has been oriented towards the establishment of "greenfield" enterprises. In fact, the same rigidities in capital and labour use that depress the profitability of domestic investment in public firms, discourage foreign participation in privatisation. Since these firms, like the others, need foreign capital and know-how to gain competitiveness and profitability, the government should consider what support to give to potential foreign investors in order to partly offset the disincentive stemming from these rigidities. In so doing, they would not discriminate against domestic investors because the latter already benefit from mass privatisation free of charge and other preferences. A fourth problem is represented by the shortage of entrepreneurs. These countries have at their disposal a substantial number of good managers of production processes but have also a shortfall of entrepreneurs, i.e. people that are able to launch new production initiatives and manage business risk. The transfer of ownership into private hands does not lead, on its own, to a rapid conversion of good production managers into good entrepreneurs who are capable of maximising the value of their enterprise within the constraints of a competitive market economy. Therefore, to ensure that privatisation leads to development of viable enterprises, it has to be coupled with a government action aimed at promoting entrepreneurship on an economy-wide scale. A fifth problem concerns the uneven quality of the enterprises which have still to be privatised. In the initial phase governments have disposed mostly of the firms which are in better conditions and can attract investors' attention. As privatisation advances, what are on offer are the less attractive firms and demand for them by private investors might be lacking. In this case governments are faced with the choice between liquidation and restructuring before privatisation. Both options are costly and difficult to implement since they involve either dealing with the resulting unemployment and liability settlement, which also affects banks' solvency, or planning and implementing a business-oriented restructuring. Hence, with progress in privatisation, its interdependence with progress in other policies, such as industrial, social and financial policies, becomes critical for making further headway. Privatisation of defence industries raises a number of problems that leave little in common with the general issue of privatisation. The difficulties in the defence sector derive basically from a shift in the composition of the demand in the economy: military procurement has been cut back sharply in a short period and government subventions to military industries have been curtailed. At the same time demand for civilian goods has risen but in a new context of markets open to competition and of a decline of per-capita income levels for large sections of the population. Other peculiar difficulties are the exclusive dependence of the economy of certain regions on military industries, the relatively high incidence of laboratories and test facilities over total facilities, the secrecy surrounding many technologies and the coexistence within the military sector of a considerable production of consumer goods and machine tools. For instance, in the former Soviet Union, it is estimated that more than half of consumer goods were produced by the military-industrial complex. To assess the role and problems of privatisation in dealing with these difficulties the governments have, first, to clarify the objectives to be pursued. Thus, the first problem to be tackled is to decide whether to pursue a reallocation of human and physical capital as well as technologies towards other sectors of the economy or other enterprises which are expanding in the new market-based economic system, or to continue investing in the military industries to produce the new range of goods and services requested by the market. Related to this problem is a second one pertaining to the structure of ownership. The question is whether the government should retain ownership of facilities working for the market and aim at upgrading their management, or should transfer ownership to the private sector, being that more market- and business-oriented. Likewise, as to defence-oriented production facilities, the question is whether the national security concerns could be addressed through other means than direct government ownership of these facilities. In other words, should the government be only on the demand side of the economy, leaving the supply side for both military and civilian goods exclusively in private hands? Or should the government turn military industries into conglomerate companies which own both civilian and military-oriented companies and which can use resources generated in one group of companies to support the other. Assuming that a certain portion of the current defence industry has to be privatised, another question emerges: whether to privatise individual assets, or entire plants, or to extend privatisation to military technology for the purpose of allowing their use in non-military sectors. All these questions have to receive an answer at the political level rather than at the military one since these involve many considerations which lie outside the military realm and also concern the future structure and development of the economy. From an economic point of view, it would seem appropriate that all facilities working for the market be transferred to the private sector because the latter is in the best position to compete in the market place. It is not clear whether countries with a sizeable defence industry, such as Russia, have moved in the direction of drawing a clear demarcation line between the core defence activities to be retained in the public sector for security reasons and the other activities which can be privatised. By the end of 1993 Russia had privatised more than 270 defence-related enterprises and corporatised another 760. In the same period it is estimated that more than 1.8 million workers had left the defence sector. In view of all these problems afflicting the defence industry, it does not seem that privatisation per se is the main solution. It is, however, an important component of a strategy which starts with "unbundling" the defence industry in to privatisable and non-privatisable assets, then proceeds with privatising all that is not related to ÒcoreÓ national security, and eventually leads to a restructuring of privatised enterprises by private entrepreneurs. Enterprise restructuring is, nevertheless, a difficult task since it requires converting military firms to the logic and demands of the market. The experience of the US after the World War II and that of other OECD countries more recently shows that plant conversion seldom succeeds because the military enterprise culture does not encompass critical elements for being successful in the market place, such as cost-effectiveness, market analysis, financial management and marketing. It has often been the case that OECD countries, instead of converting or privatising defence plants, have found it more appropriate to liquidate these assets or to scrap them outright. Recent surveys of Western investors also confirm this conclusion as they indicate a clear preference for establishing new plants in the reforming economies rather than converting existing defence plants. Hence, it seems that the reforming countries should focus their response to the problems of their defence industry in directions other than enterprise privatisation. Specifically, they should aim at creating an environment conducive to the creation of new enterprises and new job opportunities. This has to be supported by consistent social, credit and labour-market policies directed to favour the reallocation of production factors. For regions which are particularly hit by defence expenditure cut-backs, it is also necessary to resort to regional development plans. Leaving aside defence privatisation, what future can be envisaged for the general privatisation process in the next five years, starting from the present situation and the many problems already mentioned? In the countries that have made limited progress so far, an acceleration of the pace of privatisation seems unlikely unless a new high wave of mass privatisation for free is launched. As for the others, mainly the states of the former USSR who have lagged behind, an acceleration is possible. The pace of privatisation will likely depend on two conditions: a) the stringency of the public budget constraint which might deprive public firms of critical support; and b) the pace of output recovery since a revival of economic activities might ease the social costs of privatisation. Overall, only in one or two countries, such as the Czech Republic and Russia, enterprise privatisation is expected to be completed by 1997. For the others, privatisation will continue to be a slow process, which might become hostage to social and political compromises, and might be restricted to a fraction of existing public enterprises. In contrast, a rise in the demand for the purchase of public firms could stem from the expected easing of the current constraints represented by the weakness of the legal and institutional framework of the economy, the shortage of domestic capital and the limitations in entrepreneurial skills. This is not, however, sufficient to spur the authorities to accelerate privatisation, unless significant benefits are expected, such as significant revenue for the currently strained public finances or considerable capital in-flows for the balance of payments. In the face of these conflicting pressures, it is likely that in the next five years the development of the private sector would have to rely more on new entrepreneurial initiatives than on newly privatised public enterprises. Surprisingly, it might be the case that the autonomous expansion of the private sector could offer a window of opportunity for facilitating speedier privatisation. By attracting labour currently employed in public firms, the private sector could alleviate the social impact of privatisation, and defuse its most contentious aspects. The outcome could be to bring to manageable proportions either the closing-down of public firms or their radical restructuring for the purpose of making them competitive. In other words, the problem of privatisation could disappear since public firms could either be liquidated and their production assets sold if not written off, or they could be turned into viable firms managed along business-oriented criteria and in no need of privatisation. Regardless of whatever scenario would become reality, it is likely that in most of these countries the economic system would evolve in the coming years into a sort of "mixed capitalism", with private firms co-existing and competing with an important sector made out of firms owned by public authorities. In such a context, the major concerns for the purpose of attaining efficiency gains for the economy as a whole are both to create the framework conditions for private economic initiative to materialise and prosper, and to ensure evenhanded treatment for private firms and public ones so as not to distort competition. This would imply the discontinuation of the many preferences in financial and regulatory terms that public firms have so far enjoyed. Among the various forms of privatisation, free ownership transfer and management or employee buy-out at national prices will continue to prevail over trade sales although the balance between them might shift towards sales if considerable proceeds or employment or investment guarantees will be provided by buyers outside the firm. In any case, the initial ownership transfer will be just the first phase of a process of ownership restructuring which will continue after privatisation. A new wave of ownership reshuffle is to be expected in the next five years with the result of a concentration of corporate governance in fewer hands than at the moment of privatisation. The wide diffusion of shares among the population does not necessarily reflect people's desire to hold them and to exercise the inherent ownership rights over the way companies are managed. It is instead dictated by the two needs of dealing with concerns over the distribution of the accumulated social wealth and implanting a new economic culture among people. In spite of these needs, the reallocation of shares seems inevitable in order to allow a mechanism of control over and accountability of management to emerge in the face of the current fragmentation of ownership. Three components are crucial to this end: a) investment funds or mutual funds; b) secondary markets; c) the banking system. Investment funds and similar institutions are bound to play a prominent role in controlling enterprises' management as intended by the authorities in launching mass privatisation. Building on these foundations, their role could easily develop into providing equity capital to new enterprises by attracting and mobilising private savings. Their ability to monitor the state of health of firms and their diversification of risks offer clear advantages to investors over a direct investment in enterprises' stocks. Secondary markets for stocks and assets have begun to develop in these countries as the principal mechanism for adjusting the portfolio composition of investors and to provide liquidity to share holders. Their expansion has been hampered in some countries, such as Russia, by temporary preclusions of subsequent ownership transfers. With the progress in privatisation and a wider diffusion of shares, pressure for the abolition of these constraints will increase. A significant development of secondary markets could hence be envisaged. Such a development needs, however, to be sustained by improvements in the regulatory framework of markets and in the requirements for transparency of information on enterprises and financial institutions. Apart from secondary markets, stock exchange markets could become an important instrument for privatisation by the end of this decade. So far only a small number of firms have been sold in the markets (15% of total book value privatised in Hungary and a lower percentage in Poland). As these markets mature, it can be expected that the number of public offerings of stocks will rise. This will concern both entire companies' stocks and minority stakes retained by governments after the initial privatisation. This trend is already evident: Hungary plans to sell large companies through the Budapest Stock Exchange and the Czech National Property Fund is selling shares retained after the first wave of voucher privatisation. Despite its current weakness, the banking system is also essential in supporting both privatisation and post-privatisation. Its role will strengthen to the extent that banks are directly involved in the restructuring of the liabilities of the enterprises to be privatised. A certain number of debt/equity swaps will take place and the increasing presence of stocks among banks' assets will heavily influence the operational profile of the banking system: the model of "universal bank" might become the predominant one. Banks will also fulfil the essential function of supplying liquidity to investors and stock market participants. Without such support, secondary markets can hardly develop into efficient instruments for resources allocation and would remain rather unpredictable, with discontinuous patterns in price evolution. As regards the role of foreign capital, there are now very few elements that might lead to an increasing interest of foreign companies in participating in privatisation, given several internal or operational constraints that accompany privatisation. The participation of foreign investors might instead rise in the post-privatisation reallocation of ownership, but this would demand major improvements in the performance of stock markets and financial intermediaries, such as investment funds. Finally, two considerations on the expected benefits of privatisation. Welfare gains for the economy as a whole do not stem simply from privatisation but from its combination with competition. So far there has been limited support for demonopolisation prior to privatisation, particularly among those interested in acquiring public firms or that have already acquired them. Nor has liberalisation of foreign trade, profit regulations and competition laws been adequate to reduce the market power of monopolists. In the absence of demonopolisation authorities might refrain from relinquishing their ownership of de-facto monopolist firms. This does not seem the appropriate response because privatisation of predominant market suppliers might bring about higher efficiency gains than in the opposite case if it is accompanied by more stringent regulations aimed at reducing the market power of major domestic suppliers and by incentives for new competitors to enter the market. At any rate, the commitments taken by several CEECs and NIS to lower further their trade barriers in the next few years, particularly vis-a-vis European companies, is bound to make their markets much more competitive than at present by the end of this decade. As to the impact on public finances, privatisation is not likely to generate large revenues for the budget, assuming the prevalence of methods other than trade sales. Some relief for public expenditure might however derive from the disposal or liquidation of firms, provided that the consequent social costs and social expenditures are not substantial. If some large enterprises are retained in the public sector for several years a hidden burden would remain in the budget. This will prompt the authorities to restructure these enterprises and to establish objective criteria for the accountability of management. Hungary, Poland and Romania are already considering entering into contracts with management groups to conduct operational restructuring and manage these enterprises. Such contracts, which include ownership incentives, might expand in the near future and prove successful in rehabilitating enterprises. In conclusion, it has to be stressed that in a market economy, privately owned firms generally outperform public firms in cost-effectiveness, efficiency and competitiveness. Hence, in order to raise public welfare in the "mixed-capitalism" that will characterise these economies for at least this decade, privatisation has to remain a constant objective of governments and should continue to be pursued in spite of the difficulties. In this respect, the main challenge for these governments is not just to achieve a successful restructuring of firms still kept under public ownership but to be able to recognise when the time has come for these firms to be privatised. If these governments fail in taking a timely decision in this sense, they will likely fall into the old trap of inefficiencies and subsidies. In other words, they will show that they have not learned enough from the experience of OECD countries that after decades of complacency are now forced by their economic ills to push privatisation through. ---------------------------------------------------------- Copyright 1994 NATO All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means: electronic, electrostatic, magnetic tape, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without permission in writing from the copyright holders. Authorization may be requested for redistribution of the text on a non commercial base by research and educational services. Requests should be addressed to the Economics Directorate, NATO, via e-mail 'scheurweghs@hq.nato.int'. First edition 1994 ISBN 92-845-0079-6 This is the latest in a series bringing together papers presented at the NATO colloquia organised by the NATO Economics Directorate and Office of Information and Press on economic issues in the former USSR and Central and East European countries. For further information please write to the Director, Office of Information and Press, 1110 Brussels, Belgium. The articles contained in this volume represent the views of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the official opinion or policy of member governments or NATO.